From the 1965 Annual Report of the United States Steel Corporation.
Private enterprise is freedom to produce and sell, and freedom to buy and consume; and the consumer, as well as the producer, is an integral part of the private enterprise system — indeed, the consumer also is in a way a private enterpriser. As an economic system, private enterprise is characterized by competition, open markets, private ownership, and private initiative. Producers take production initiative on the basis of price and profit-and-loss signals essentially given by consumers.
Thus on the firing line of open competitive production is the business firm — an individual or a group of individuals. The firm pools the savings and plans of investors and the talents and energies of employees with the expectancy of meeting some particular demand of the consumers and with the hope of earning a profit for the owners. To prosper — in-deed to survive — the firm must serve the public, that is, the public interest. But running a business is a risky operation as the public is a hard taskmaster, quick to switch its life-or-death patronage from any firm it deems lacking.
Private enterprise is open to all comers. Anybody with an idea for enterprise and the requisite capital is free to start a business. Quite a few people, some even without any money of their own, have had such ideas. In fact, there are now some 11 million businesses, including farms, in the United States. The overwhelming proportion are sole proprietorships and partnerships and only about 11 per cent of the total are corporations….
The Consumer’s Interest
The consumer’s interest in private enterprise is in getting more and more for less and less — with maximum freedom of choice. So naturally the consumer — Mr. Everybody, the entire American public — is keenly interested in private enterprise, because private enterprise is the consumer’s servant, and consumer choice is the heart of private enterprise.
Thus through the cash register or company order book, through his power of purchase or nonpurchase, the customer speaks to and — in the sense that actions speak louder than words — for American business. Moreover, he possesses virtually an absolute veto over every major decision of a firm. He largely decides the public interest in private enterprise because, collectively, he is the public — as well as a key participant in the business system.
His power is crucial. Every cost of doing business — every tax, wage, salary, fringe benefit, material cost, interest payment, and so on — must be ultimately sought from one and only one source, the cost-aware customer.
His purchase therefore sanctions a firm’s prices, makes production and jobs possible, and sustains the very life of the business. In effect he assigns profits to those firms he deems in his interest — the public interest — and these firms prosper and expand. At the same time he assigns losses to those firms he deems not in his interest — the public interest — and these firms, unless they mend their ways, weaken and eventually fail. Thus, under private enterprise it is said, wisely, that the customer is king — the consumer is sovereign.
To be sure, consumer sovereignty is not absolute; the producer also has freedom of choice. He can choose his industry or field of endeavor, where and how he wishes to operate, the prices he would like to get, but in the long run he cannot sell below cost nor above competitive prices. Nevertheless, it is the consumer who ultimately decides in effect what and how much will be produced, by whom, and at what price it will be sold.
Another point on the consumer’s interest: The marketplace is democratic to an almost unimaginable degree in the political realm. Every day is Election Day in the market. Each purchase is a vote, and a company’s sales is its tabulation of consumers’ ballots, the customers’ dollar. For each company there is neither tenure nor a fixed term of office. A big business can be voted small, a small business can be voted big, and any business can be voted out of office.
So through his dollar votes the consumer, who may also be an employee or investor or both, ever adjusts supply— and suppliers — to demand, to the public interest.
The Employee’s Interest
The employee’s interest in private enterprise is his job, for it is the source of his well-being. He too is keenly interested in maximum freedom of choice. He is born a free man in a country in which opportunity and equality of opportunity are unexcelled in the world. He can choose his career from available opportunities, decide how hard he wishes to pursue it, select where to live and work. These are his personal decisions.
Naturally, he is also interested in business growth, which means job opportunity growth and wage and salary growth. American wage and salary scales are far and away the highest in the world, and the job-sustaining and job-creating ability of the private enterprise system, for all the talk of automation, has never been in greater evidence.
He should likewise be interested in profits. Some assert that wages and profits are in opposition, that profits exist only at the expense of wages. Nothing could be further from the truth. Private enterprise is based on competition and cooperation — not conflict. Labor and capital are in natural partnership— each is dependent upon the other. And from the employee’s point of view, the more capital the better; and since profit attracts capital, the more profit the better. For capital is the key to productivity, and out of improving productivity alone comes all continuing real wage and salary improvement as well as gains to consumers, governments, and investors.
Little wonder, then, that capital investment per employee in America clearly exceeds capital investment per employee in all other countries. It follows that American wages and employee benefits arise out of America’s tremendous capital productivity which, in turn, arises out of the private enterprise system. Plainly, these wages and benefits — and job opportunities — are not bestowed by benevolent governments nor, for that matter, by aggressive union leaders or magnanimous business employers.
The consumer in the final analysis is the real employer; his purchase creates job opportunities. It is his dollar that meets the payroll. It is his nonpurchase which rejects uneconomic wage scales or shoddy workmanship, and workers so rejected may well find little consolation in being the highest-priced and most unemployed workers in the world. So, in a very real sense, the employee doesn’t work for the employer; he works for the consumer.
Thus job-creation will continue to go on, provided wage rates are responsive to the consumer’s interest; provided savers and investors, in their investment function of providing tools, have the incentive to go forward; and provided the intricate price mechanism that governs the billions of daily transactions through innumerable continually changing prices in the American economy remains self-governing.
The Government’s Interest
The government’s interest in private enterprise should be in the vitality of business. Business can prosper, economic growth can continue, and tax revenues can be sustained only when essential governmental duties are properly performed. Such duties include maintaining law and order, safeguarding property and contracts, and securing the individual from violence from within or without.
But governments can overreach themselves and set back the cause of “Life, Liberty, and the pursuit of Happiness.” For the tendency of governments throughout history has been to assume supreme economic insight, to inflate the money supply, to introduce rigidity (“stability”) into economic affairs, to favor some groups at the expense of others, to fix “reasonable” prices and “reasonable” profits; in short, to intervene in normal everyday business decisions and upset the entire competitive mechanism, all too frequently in the name of “the public interest.”
The Investor’s Interest
The investor’s interest in private enterprise is in putting his money to work profitably. This is vital to him, to private enterprise, to government, and to the entire American society. He is one of millions of direct investors, including 20 million shareholders, who have supplied job-creating capital to business through risking their savings. In addition, he is one of more than 100 million indirect investors who, through their savings deposits, insurance policies, and pension fund participation, invest in American business. The investor’s key problem: He must decide where and how to invest. In this he is motivated by powerful, if quite different, drives — the hope of gain and the fear of loss. The investor readily recognizes that management plays a crucial role, that enterprise and risk go hand in hand, that today’s return on operations could turn into tomorrow’s loss.
Importantly, however, the investor is not committed to his investments. He is also a free agent — most willing to hold or even increase his investments when he deems their yields right and risks reasonable. But, at the same time, whenever he thinks yields are unsatisfactory or risks too great, he can switch his investments — sell his stocks, bonds, or properties and use the proceeds for other investments — or, if he lacks confidence in the future, he may not invest at all. In any event, investing or disinvesting, he keeps a constant watch on profitability which, as noted, is essentially a signal from consumers.
Through the profit incentive, then, comes a mighty flow of invested savings: the capital that makes modern private enterprise possible; that keeps it on its toes; that provides employees with tools — factories and machinery — which make job opportunities, high productivity, and high wages a reality; that enables producers to furnish the goods and services which the consumer desires at prices he is willing to pay. Thus, three factors of overriding importance govern the investor’s interest: savings, confidence in the future, and the prospect of profit.
Thus, private enterprise and the decisions of private enterprise —decisions shared by all Americans — inherently and most democratically reflect the public’s wishes, the public’s interest. Interference with the decisions of private enterprise in the name of the public interest thus amounts, ironically, to interference with the public interest. For the decisions of private enterprise are the decisions of the people, by the people, for the people.
***
Political Decisions
The expansion of government to its present scale has politicalized virtually all economic life. The wages being paid most workers today are political wages, reflecting political pressures rather than anything that might be considered the normal working of supply and demand. The prices farmers receive are political prices. The profits business is earning are political profits. The savings people hold have become political savings, since their real value is subject to abrupt depreciation by political decisions.
SAMUEL LUBELL, The Future of American Politics